Corporate Social Responsibility in an Experimental Market
Commenced in January 2007
Frequency: Monthly
Edition: International
Paper Count: 33122
Corporate Social Responsibility in an Experimental Market

Authors: Nikolaos Georgantzis, Efi Vasileiou

Abstract:

We present results from experimental price-setting oligopolies in which green firms undertake different levels of energy-saving investments motivated by public subsidies and demand-side advantages. We find that consumers reveal higher willingness to pay for greener sellers’ products. This observation in conjunction to the fact that greener sellers set higher prices is compatible with the use and interpretation of energy-saving behaviour as a differentiation strategy. However, sellers do not exploit the resulting advantage through sufficiently high price-cost margins, because they seem trapped into “run to stay still” competition. Regarding the use of public subsidies to energy-saving sellers we uncover an undesirable crowding-out effect of consumers’ intrinsic tendency to support green manufacturers. Namely, consumers may be less willing to support a green seller whose energy-saving strategy entails a direct financial benefit. Finally, we disentangle two alternative motivations for consumer’s attractions to pro-social firms; first, the self-interested recognition of the firm’s contribution to the public and private welfare and, second, the need to compensate a firm for the cost entailed in each pro-social action. Our results show the prevalence of the former over the latter.

Keywords: Corporate social responsibility, energy savings, public good, experiments, vertical differentiation, altruism.

Digital Object Identifier (DOI): doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.1093976

Procedia APA BibTeX Chicago EndNote Harvard JSON MLA RIS XML ISO 690 PDF Downloads 2118

References:


[1] Friedman, M. (1970), "The Social Responsibility of Business Is to Increase Its Profits,” The New York Times Magazine, (13 September) 32–33, 122, 126.
[2] McWilliams, A. & Wright, P.M. (2006), "Corporate Social Responsibility: Strategic Implications,” Journal of Management Studies, 43, 1-18.
[3] Husted, B.W. & De Jesus Salazar, J. (2006), "Taking Friedman seriously: maximizing profits and social performance,” Journal of Management Studies, 43, 75–91
[4] Baron, D. (2001), "Private Politics, Corporate Social Responsibility and Integrated Strategy,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 10, 7-45.
[5] Mussa, M. & Rosen, S. (1978), "Monopoly and product quality,” Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 301–317.
[6] Gabszewicz, J.J. &Thisse, J.F. (1979), "Price competition, quality and income disparities,” Journal of Economic Theory, 20, 340-359.
[7] Shaked, A. & Sutton, J. (1982), Relaxing Price Competition through Product Differentiation, Review of Economic Studies, 49, 3-13.
[8] Shaked, A. & Sutton, J. (1983), Natural Oligopolies, Econometrica, 51, 1469-83.
[9] Crampes, C. & Hollander, A. (1995), "Duopoly and Quality Standards,” European Economic Review, 39, 71-82.
[10] Lutz, S. Lyon, T.P. Maxwell, J.W. (2000), "Quality leadership when regulatory standards are forthcoming,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 48, 331–48.
[11] Barreda, I. García-Gallego, A. Georgantzís, N. Jaramillo-Gutiérrez, A., &Sabater-Grande, G. (2011), "An Experiment on the Motivation and the Effects of Socially Responsible Market Behavior,” International Journal of Ecological Economics and Statistics, 23, 105-128.
[12] Cason, T.N. &Gangadharan L. (2002), "Environmental labeling and incomplete consumer information in laboratory markets,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 43, 113–134.
[13] Rode, J.R. Hogarth, M. & Le Menestrel, M. (2008), "Ethical differentiation and market behavior: An experimental approach,” Journal of Economic Behaviour and Organization, 66, 265-280.