Elections, Checks and Balances, and Government Expenditures: Empirical Evidence for Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan
Commenced in January 2007
Frequency: Monthly
Edition: International
Paper Count: 32795
Elections, Checks and Balances, and Government Expenditures: Empirical Evidence for Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan

Authors: Yuan-Hong Ho, Chiung-Ju Huang

Abstract:

Previous studies on political budget cycles (PBCs) implicitly assume the executive has full discretion power over fiscal policy, neglecting the role of checks and balances of the legislature. This paper goes beyond traditional PBCs models and sheds light on the case study of Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan over the 1988-2007 periods. Based on the results, we find no evidence of electoral impacts on the public expenditures in South Korean and Taiwan's congressional elections. We also noted that PBCs are found on Taiwan-s government expenditures during our sample periods. Furthermore, the results also show that Japan-s legislature has a significant checks and balances on government-s expenditures. However, empirical results show that the legislature veto player in Taiwan neither has effect on the reduction of public expenditures, nor has the moderating effect over Taiwan-s political budget cycles, albeit that they are statistically insignificant.We suggest that the existence of PBCs in Taiwan is due to a weaker systemof checks and balances. Our conjecture is that Taiwan either has no legislative veto player or has observed low compliance to the law during the time period examined in our study.

Keywords: Checks and balances, compliance to the law, political budget cycles, veto player.

Digital Object Identifier (DOI): doi.org/10.5281/zenodo.1078747

Procedia APA BibTeX Chicago EndNote Harvard JSON MLA RIS XML ISO 690 PDF Downloads 1686

References:


[1] W. Nordhaus, "The political business cycle," Review of Economic Studies, 1975, vol. 42, pp. l69-190.
[2] K. Rogoff, and A. Sibert, "Elections and macroeconomic policy cycles," Review of Economic Studies, 1988, vol. 55, pp. 1-16.
[3] L. Schuknecht, "Political business cycles and fiscal policies in developing countries," KYKLOS, 1996, vol. 49, pp. 155-170.
[4] M. Hallerberg, and J. von Hagen, "Electoral institutions, cabinet negotiations, and budget deficits in the European Union," in Fiscal Institutions and Fiscal Performance, J. Poterba and J. von Hagen, Ed. University of Chicago Press, Chicago, 1999.
[5] J. Alt, and D. Lassen, "Transparency, political polarization and political budget cycles in OECD countries," American Journal of Political Science, 2006, vol. 50, pp. 530-550.
[6] A. Alesina, and G. Tabellini, "Why do politicians delegate?" NBER working paper, no.1531, 2005.
[7] M. Shi, and J. Svensson, "Political budget cycles: do they differ across countries and why?" Journal of Public Economics, 2006, vol.90, pp. 1367-1389.
[8] A. Alesina, and N. Roubini, Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. Cambridge, MA: MIT press, 1997.
[9] R. Alesina, H. Hausmann, and E. Stein, "Budget institutions and fiscal performance in Latin America," Journal of Development Economics, 1999, vol. 59, no. 2, pp. 253-273.
[10] A. Block, "Political business cycles, democratization, and economic reform: the case of Africa,"Journal of Development Economics, 2002, vol. 67, pp. 205-228.
[11] M. d. l. A. Gonzales, "Do changes in democracy affect the political budget cycle? evidence from Mexico," Review of Developmental Economics, 2002, vol. 6, no. 2, pp. 204-224.
[12] J. Klomp, and J. De Haan, "Do political budget cycles really exist?" Applied Economics, 2013, vol. 45, pp. 329-341.
[13] M. Kraemer, "Electoral budget cycles in Latin America and Caribbean: incidence, causes and political futility," Inter-American Development Bank working paper, Washington DC, 1997.
[14] A. Brender, "The effect of fiscal performance on local government election results in Israel: 1989-1998," Journal of Public Economics, 2003, vol. 87, pp. 2187-2205.
[15] A. Drazen, and M. Eslava, "Electoral manipulation via expenditure composition: theory and evidence," NBER working paper, no. 11085. 2005.
[16] A. Drazen, and M. Eslava, "Electoral manipulation via voter-friendly spending: theory and evidence," Journal of Development Economics, 2010, vol. 32, pp. 39-52.
[17] L. Schuknecht, "Fiscal policy cycles and public expenditure in developing countries," Public Choice, 2000, vol. 102, pp. 115-30.
[18] A. Drazen, "The political business cycles after 25 years,"in NBER macroeconomics annual, B. Bernake, and K. Rogoff, Ed. Boston: MIT Press, 2001, pp. 75-117
[19] T. Persson, and G. Tabellini, Do electoral cycles differ across political systems, mimeo, IIES, Stockholm University, 2002.
[20] O. Diallo, "Tortuous road toward countercyclical fiscal policy: Lessons from democratized sub-Saharan Africa," Journal of Policy Modeling, 2009, vol. 31, pp. 36-50.
[21] A. Brender, and A. Drazen, "Political budget cycles in new versus established democracies," Journal ofMonetary Economics, 2005, vol. 52, pp. 1271-1295.
[22] T. Persson, and G. Tabellini, "The economic effect of constitutions: what do the data say,"Cambridge, MA: MIT press, 2003.
[23] T. Persson, and G. Tabellini, "Constitutional rules and fiscal policy outcomes," The American Economic Review, 2004, vol. 94, no. 1, pp. 25-45.
[24] J. von Hagen, and I. Harden, "Budget processes and commitment to fiscal discipline," European Economic Review, 1995, vol. 39, pp. 771-79.
[25] J. Henisz, "Political institutions and policy volatility," Economics and Politics, 2004, vol. 16, no. 1, pp. 1-27.
[26] M. Streb, D. Lema, and G. Torrens, "Checks and balances on political budget cycles: cross-country evidence,"KYKLOS, 2009, vol. 62, no. 3, pp. 426-447.
[27] S. Fabrizio, and A. Mody, "Can budget institutions counteract political indiscipline?"Economic Policy, pp. 689-739, October 2006.
[28] M. Streb, and G. Torrens, "Making rules credible: divided government and political budget cycles," Working paper, Universidad del Cema, 2009.
[29] B. Albuquerque, "Fiscal institutions and public spending volatility in Europe," Estudos e Documentos de Trabalho working papers, 2010.
[30] J. Henisz, POLCON 2005 codebook, manuscript, University of Pennsylvania, 2005.
[31] C. W. J. Granger, and P. Newbold, "Spurious regression in econometrics," Journal of Econometrics, 1974, vol. 2, pp. 111-120.
[32] R. Engle, and C. W. J. Granger, "Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing," Econometrica, 1987, vol. 55, pp. 251-276.
[33] A. Dickey, and W. Fuller, "Likelihood ratio statistics for autoregressive time series with a unit root," Econometrica, 1981, vol.49, pp. 1057-1072.
[34] C. Phillips, and P. Perron, "Testing for a unit root in time series regression," Biometrika, 1988, vol. 75, pp. 335-346.
[35] D. Kwiatkowski, C. Phillips, P. Schmidt and Y. Shin, "Testing the null hypothesis of stationarity against the alternative of a unit root," Journal of Econometrics, 1992, vol. 1, pp. 159-178.
[36] P. Perron, "The great crash, the oil price shock and the unit root hypothesis,"Econometrica, 1989, vol. 57, no. 6, pp. 1361-1401.
[37] P. Perron, "Testing for a unit root in a time series with a changing mean," Journal of Business Economics and Statistics, 1990, vol. 8, no. 2, pp. 153-162.
[38] E. Zivot, and D.W. K. Andrews, "Further evidence on the great crash, the oil-price shock, and the unit root hypothesis," Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 1992, vol. 10, pp. 251-270.
[39] A. Zellner, "An efficient method of estimating seemingly unrelated regression and tests for aggregation bias," Journal of the American Statistical association, pp. 348-368, June, 1962.